Economics

From Wiki
Jump to: navigation, search

The most recent and complete economic model documentation is available on Pardee's website. Although the text in this interactive system is, for some IFs models, often significantly out of date, you may still find the basic description useful to you.

The economics model of IFs forecasting system draws on two general modeling traditions. The first is the dynamic growth model of classical economics. Within IFs the growth rates of labor force, capital stock, and multifactor productivity largely determine the overall size of production and therefore of the economy. The second tradition is the general equilibrium model of neo-classical economics. IFs contains a six-sector (agriculture, raw materials, energy, manufactures, services, and ICT) equilibrium-seeking representation of domestic supply, domestic demand, and trade. Further, the goods and services market representation is embedded in a larger social accounting matrix structure that introduces the behavior of household, firm, and government agent classes and the financial flows they determine. 

Goods and Services Market

 

System/Subsystem
Goods and Services
Organizing Structure
Endogenously driven production function represented within a dynamic general equilibrium-seeking model
Stocks
Capital, labor, accumulated technology
Flows
Production, consumption, trade, investment
Key Aggregate  Relationships 
(illustrative, not comprehensive)
Production function with endogenous technological change; price movements equilibrate markets over time
Key Agent-Class Behavior  Relationships
(illustrative, not comprehensive)
Households and work/leisure, consumption, and female participation patterns;
 
Firms and investment;
 
Government decisions on revenues and on both direct expenditures and transfer payments

Households, firms, and the government interact via markets in goods and services. There are obvious stock and flow components of markets that are desirable and infrequently changed in model representation. Perhaps the most important key aggregate relationship is the production function. Although the firm is an implicit agent-class in that function, the relationships of production even to capital and labor inputs, much less to the variety of technological and social and human capital elements that enter a specification of endogenous productivity change (Solow 1957; Romer 1994), involve multiple agent-classes. In the representation of the market now in IFs there are also many key agent-class relationships as suggested by the table.

 

Financial Flows / Social Accounting

 

System/Subsystem
Financial
Organizing Structure
Market plus socio-political transfers in Social Accounting Matrix (SAM)
Stocks
Government, firm, household assets/debts
Flows
Savings, consumption, FDI, foreign Aid, IFI credits/grants, government expenditures (military, health, education, other) and transfers (pensions and social transfers)
Key Aggregate  Relationships 
(illustrative, not comprehensive)
Exchange rate, movements with net asset/current account level; interest rate movements with savings and investment
Key Agent-Class Behavior  Relationships
(illustrative, not comprehensive)
Household savings/consumption;
 
Firm investment/profit returns and FDI decisions;
 
Government revenue, expenditure/transfer payments;
 
IFI credits and grants

Households, firms, and the government interact in markets, but more broadly also via financial flows, including those related to the market (like foreign direct investment), but extending also to those that have a socio-political basis (like government to household transfers). A key structural representation is the Social Accounting Matrix (SAM).

The structural system portrayed by SAMs is well represented by stocks, flows, and key relationships. Although the traditional SAM matrix itself is a flow matrix, IFs has introduced a parallel stock matrix that captures the accumulation of assets and liabilities across various agent-classes. The dynamic elements that determine the flows within the SAM involve key relationships, such as that which constrains government spending or forces increased revenue raising when government indebtedness rises. Many of these, as indicated in the table, represent agent-class behavior.

The model can represent the behavior of households with respect to use of time for employment and leisure, the use of income for consumption and savings, and the specifics of consumption decisions across possible goods and services. And it represents the behavior of governments with respect to search for income and targeting of transfers and expenditures, in interaction with other agents including households, firms, and international financial institutions (IFIs).

IFs thus represents equilibrating markets (domestically and globally) in goods and services and in financial flows. It does not yet include labor market equilibration.

Dominant Relations: Economics

 In any long-term economic model the supply side has particular importance. In IFs, gross domestic product (GDP) is a function of multifactor productivity (MFP), capital stocks (KS), and labor inputs (LABS), all specified for each of six sectors. This approach is sometimes called a Solowian Cobb-Douglas specification, but IFs helps the user get inside the multifactor productivity term, rather than leaving it as a totally exogenous residual.

The following key dynamics are directly related to the dominant relations:

  • Multifactor productivity is a function partly of exogenous specification of an annual growth rate in it for the systemic technology leader, base rates of relative technological advance in other countries determined via an inverted U-shaped function that assumes convergence with the leader, and of an exogenously specified additive factor for control of specific regions or countries.
  • Multifactor productivity is, however, largely an endogenous function of variables determined in other models of the IFs system representing the extent of human, social, physical, and knowledge capital; their influence on production involves coefficients that the user can control.
  • Capital stock is a function of investment and depreciation rates. Endogenously determined investment can be influenced exogenously by a multiplier and the lifetime of capital can be changed.
  • Labor supply is determined from population of appropriate age in the population model (see its dominant relations and dynamics) and endogenous labor force participation rates, influenced exogenously by the growth of female participation.

The larger economic model provides also representation of and some control over sector-specific consumption patterns; trade including protectionism levels and terms of trade; taxation levels; economic freedom levels; and financial dynamics around foreign aid, borrowing, and external debt.

Social Accounting Matrix Approach in IFs

A SAM integrates a multi-sector input-output representation of an economy with the broader system of national accounts, also critically representing flows of funds among societal agents/institutions and the balance of payments with the outside world. Richard Stone is the acknowledged father of social accounting matrices, which emerged from his participation in setting up the first systems of national accounts or SNA (see Pesaran and Harcourt 1999 on Stone’s work and Stone 1986). Many others have pushed the concepts and use of SAMs forward, including Pyatt (Pyatt and Round 1985) and Thorbecke (2001). So, too, have many who have extended the use of SAMs into new frontiers. One such frontier is the additional representation of environmental inputs and outputs and the creation of what are coming to be known as social and environmental accounting matrices or SEAMs (see Pan 2000). Another very productive extension is into the connection between SAMs and technological systems of a society (see Khan 1998; Duchin 1999). It is fitting that the 1993 revision of the System of National Accounts by the United Nations began explicitly to move the SNA into the world of SAMs.

The SAM of IFs is integrated with a dynamic general equilibrium-seeking model. The structural representation is a variant and to some degree an extension of the computable general equilibrium formulations that often surround SAMs. In wrapping SAMs into CGEs, Stone was a pioneer, leading the Cambridge Growth Project with Alan Brown. That project placed SAMs into a broader modeling framework so that the effects of changes in assumptions and coefficients could be analyzed, the predecessor to the development and use of computable general equilibrium (CGE) models by the World Bank and others. Some of the Stone work continued with the evolution of the Cambridge Growth Model of the British economy (Barker and Peterson, 1987). Kehoe (1996) reviewed the emergence of applied general equilibrium (GE) models and their transformation from tools used to solve for equilibrium under changing assumptions at a single point in time to tools used for more dynamic analysis of societies.

The approach of IFs is both within these developing traditions and an extension of them on five fronts. The first extension is in universality of the SAM representation. Most SAMS are for a single country or a small number of countries or regions within them (e.g.. see Bussolo, Chemingui, and O’Connor 2002 for a multi-regional Indian SAM within a CGE). The IFs project has created a procedure for constructing relatively highly aggregated SAMs from available data for all of the countries it represents, relying upon estimated relationships to fill sometimes extensive holes in the available data. Jansen and Vos (1997: 400-416) refer to such aggregated systems as using a "Macroeconomic social Accounting Framework." Each SAM has an identical structure and they can therefore be easily compared or even aggregated (for regions of the world).

The second extension is the connecting of the universal set of SAMs through representation of the global financial system. Most SAMs treat the rest of the world as a residual category, unconnected to anything else. Because IFs contains SAMs for all countries, it is important that the rest-of –the-world categories are mutually consistent. Thus exports and imports, foreign direct investment inflows and outflows, government borrowing and lending, and many other inter-country flows must be balanced and consistent.

The third extension is a representation of stocks as well as flows. Both domestically and internationally, many flows are related to stocks. For instance, foreign direct investment inflows augment or reduce stocks of existing investment. Representing these stocks is very important from the point of view of understanding long-term dynamics of the system because those stocks, like stocks of government debt, portfolio investment, IMF credits, World Bank loans, reserve holdings, and domestic capital stock invested in various sectors, generate flows that affect the future. Specifically, the stocks of assets and liabilities will help drive the behavior of agent classes in shaping the flow matrix.

The IFs stock framework has been developed with the asset-liability concept of standard accounting method. The stock framework is also an extension of the social accounting flow matrix, and the cumulative flows over time among the agents will determine the stocks of assets or liabilities for all agents. If the inflow demands repayment or return at some point in future, it is considered as liability for that agent and an asset for the agent from which the flow came. For example, in IFs, if a government receives loans (inflow) from other countries, the stock of those loans is a liability for the recipient government and an asset for the country or countries providing the loans.

The fourth extension is temporal and builds on the third. The SAM structure described here has been embedded within a long-term global model. The economic module of IFs has many of the characteristics of a typical CGE, but the representation of stocks and related agent-class driven behavior in a consciously long-term structure introduces a quite different approach to dynamics. Instead of elasticities or multipliers on various terms in the SAM, IFs seeks to build agent-class behavior that often is algorithmic rather than automatic. To clarify this distinction with an example, instead of representing a fixed set of coefficients that determine how an infusion of additional resources to a government would be spent, IFs increasingly attempts partially to endogenize such coefficients, linking them to such longer-term dynamics as those around levels of government debt. Similarly, the World Bank as an actor or agent could base decisions about lending on a wide range of factors including subscriptions by donor states to the Bank, development level of recipients, governance capacity of recipients, existing outstanding loans, debt-to-export ratios, etc. Much of this kind of representation is in very basic form at this level of development, but the foundation is in place.

The fifth and final extension has already been discussed. In addition to the SAM, The IFs forecasting system also includes a number of other models relevant to the analysis of longer-term forecasts. For example demographic, education, health, agriculture, and energy models all provide inputs to the economic model and SAM, as well as responding to behavior within it. The effort is to provide a dynamic base for forecasts can be made well into the 21st century. It is important to quickly emphasize that such forecasts are not predictions. Instead they are scenarios to be used for thinking about possible alternative longer-term futures.


 As a graduate student in what is now the Josef Korbel School of International Studies, Anwar Hossain worked with Barry Hughes in the development of the SAM structure and database for IFs (see Hughes and Hossain 2003); his help was much appreciated.

Economic Flow Charts

Overview

This section presents several block diagrams that are central to the two major components of the economics model, the goods and services market—with special emphasis on the production function— and the broader SAM. 

The economic model represents supply, demand, and trade in each of six economic sectors: agriculture, primary energy, raw materials, manufactures, services, and information/communications technology. The model draws upon data from the Global Trade and Analysis Project (GTAP) with 57 sectors as of GTAP 8; the pre-processor collapses those into the six IFs sectors and theoretically could collapse them into a different aggregated subset.

Inventories (or stocks) are the key equilibrating variable in three negative feedback loops. As they rise, prices fall, increasing final demand (one loop), decreasing production (a second loop), and thereby in total decreasing inventories in the pursuit over time of a target value and equilibrium. Similarly, as inventories rise, capacity utilization falls, decreasing production, and restraining inventories.
Econ1.png

Physical investment and capital stocks are the key driving variables in an important positive feedback loop. As capital rises, it increases value added and GDP, increasing final demand and further increasing investment. Similarly, government social investment can increase productivity, production and inventories in another positive feedback loop.

The figure below also shows some production detail. A-matrices, which are specified dependent on the level of development (GDP per capita), allow the computation from value added of gross production and of the production that is available, after satisfaction of intersectoral flows, for meeting final demand. It is the balance of this production for final demand with actual final demand that determines whether inventories grow or decline.

The calculation of gross production (ZS) in value terms within the economic model is overridden by calculations of physical production converted to value in the agricultural and energy models when respective switches (AGON and ENON) are thrown as in the default of the IFs Base Case scenario.

Value Added

 A Cobb-Douglas production function determines value added. Thus two principal factors are capital and labor. Labor is responsive not just to population size and structure, but to the labor participation rate, including the changing role of women in the work force. Accumulated growth in the level of technology or multifactor productivity (MFP), in a "disembodied" representation (TEFF), modifies these factors. Immediate energy shortages/shocks can also affect value added.

Valueadd.png

Multifactor Productivity

The technological factor in the production function is often called multifactor productivity (MFP). The basic value of MFP is a sum of a global productivity growth rate driven by the economically advanced or leading country/region (mfpleadr ), a technological premium dependent on GDP per capita, and an exogenous or scenario factor (mfpadd ).

In addition, however, other factors affect productivity growth over time. These include a wide range of variables, such as the years of education that adults have (EDYRSAG25) and the level of economic freedom (ECONFREE), which respectively are among the variables that affect change in MFP associated with human and social capital. 

MFP.png

Economic Aggregates and Indicators

Based on value added and population, it is possible to compute GDP, GDP at purchasing power parity, and a substantial number of country/region-specific and global indicators including several that show the extent of the global North/South gap.
Econaggregatesindic.png

Household Accounts

HHaccounts.png

The most important drivers of household income is the size of value added and the share of that accruing to households. That share, divided further into unskilled and skilled households, is initialized with data from the Global Trade and Analysis Project and changes a function driven by GDP per capita. Household income is augmented by flows from government and firms (dividends and interest). Most of household income will be used for consumption, but shares will go back to the government via taxes and to savings.

Once the total of household consumption is known, if is divided across the sectors of IFs using Engel elasticities that recognize changing use of consumption as levels per capital rise




Firm Accounts

 Firms retain as income the portion of total value added that is not sent to households in return for labor provided. Income of firms functioning within a country (ownership in IFs is not designated as domestic or international) benefit from inflows of portfolio and foreign direct investment. Firms direct their income to governments in the form of tax payments, to households as dividends and interest, to the outside world as portfolio or foreign direct investment, and to savings (available for investment).
Firmaccounts.png

Government Accounts

Govtacc1.png

Government revenues come from taxes levied on households and firms. The total expenditures are a sum of two sub-categories, direct consumption and transfer payments (the latter in turn being a sum of payments for pensions/retirement and welfare.

The annual government balance is the difference between revenues and expenditures and increments or decrements government debt in absolute terms and as a portion of GDP. That stock variable in turn sends back signals to both revenue and expenditure sides of the model so as to keep the debt at reasonable levels over time.

The level of government consumption and its distribution across targets are important policy-relevant variables in the model. Government consumption is spread across several target spending categories: military health, education, traditional infrastructure, other infrastructure, research and development, other/residual, and foreign aid). The distribution to most of those categories is endogenously determined by functions, but other models in the IFs system provide special signals for military, education, and traditional infrastructure spending. Demand for military spending involves action-reaction dynamics (when a switch is turned on) and threat levels. Demand for educational and infrastructure involves full models. Demands will not equal supply and all demands are normalized to the supply, but special protection can be given to the demands for education and infrastructure spending.

Educational spending by level of education (primary, secondary, and tertiary) is further broken out of total educational spending in the education model but targets can be changed via a multiplier. 

Govtacc2.png
Savingsinvestment.png

Savings and Investment

Savings is a sum of the savings by households, firms, the government (its fiscal balance) and net foreign savings. Investment is most immediately a sum of gross capital formation and changes in inventories.

As in other parts of the IFs economic model, there will not be an exact equilibrium between savings and investment in any given time step. The system will chase equilibrium over time with the help of two mechanisms. The smoothed pattern of savings over time will affect investment. So, too, will interest rates that respond to changes in inventories or stocks of goods and services.

Trade

The trade algorithm of IFs relies on a pooled rather than bilateral trade approach. That is, it does not track exactly who trades with whom, maintaining instead information on gross exports and imports by sector and in total. The algorithm sums import demand and export capacity across all traders (in a given sector), defines world trade as the average of those two values, and then normalizes demand and capacity to the total of world trade to determine sectoral exports and imports by geographic unit.

Trade.png

International Finance

The current account depends on international loan repayments and foreign aid flows as well as on the trade balance. The exchange rate floats with the debt level (in turn responsive to the current account balance) and is the key equilibrating variable in two negative feedback loops that work via import demand and export capacity (see description of trade).

Intlfinance.png

Income Distribution

Domestic income distribution is represented by the Gini coefficient. That is calculated with a Lorenz curve that looks at the share of population and income held by the only two subgroups for which we have that information, namely unskilled an
Incomedist.png
d skilled households. That part of the calculation is fundamentally mechanical. The complicated part of the specification is the division of the population into unskilled and skilled labor portions and thus households. We have built formulations for that driven by the formal years of education attained by adults and the GDP per capita.

Given domestic Gini indices, it is also possible to compute global Gini indices, both treating countries as wholes (GINI) and computing across the world at the household level (GINIFULL).













Poverty

The calculation of poverty levels is fairly straightforward if one has the average level of consumption per capita (or income) and its distribution as indicated by the Gini index (and if one assumes that the distribution underlying the Gini index is log-normal). The internal calculation using those variables will, however, almost inevitably produce a rate of poverty at odds with the provided by national surveys. We therefore compute a ratio of those in the first year to allow adjustment in forecast years of the values from the lognormal calculation.

As a rough check on the values produced by lognormal calculation we also compute a value of poverty estimated from a cross-sectional function linking GDP per capita (and PPP) and Gini to rates of poverty.

Poverty.png

Economic Equations 

Overview 

The growth portion of the goods and services module responds to endogenous labor supply growth (from the demographic model), endogenous capital stock growth (with a variety of influences on the investment level), and a mixture of endogenous and exogenous specification of advance in multifactor productivity (MFP). The endogenous portion of MFP represents a combination of convergence and country-specific elements that together create a conditional convergence formulation.

The equilibrium-seeking portion of the goods and services market module uses increases or decreases in inventories and prices (by sector) to balance demand and supply. Inventory stocks in each sector serve as buffers to reconcile demand and supply temporarily. Prices respond to stock levels. The central equilibrium problem that the module must address is maintaining domestic and global balance between supply and demand in each of the sectors of the model. IFs relies on three principal mechanisms to assure equilibrium in each sector: (1) price-driven changes in domestic demand; (2) price-driven changes in trade (IFs represents trade and global financial flows in pooled rather than bilateral form); and (3) stock-driven changes in investment by destination (changes in investment patterns could also be price-driven, but IFs uses stocks because of its recursive structure, so as to avoid a 2-year time delay in the response of investment).

The economic model makes no attempt through iteration or simultaneous solution to obtain exact equilibrium in any time point. In addition to being observationally obvious, Kornai (1971) and others have, of course, argued that real world economic systems are not in exact equilibrium at any time point, in spite of the convenience of such assumptions for much of economic analysis. Similarly, the SARUM global model (Systems Analysis Research Unit 1977) and GLOBUS (Hughes 1987) used buffer systems similar to that of IFs with the model "chasing" equilibrium over time.

Two "physical" or "commodity" models in IFs, agriculture and energy, have structures very similar to each other and to the economic model. They have partial equilibrium structures that optionally, and in the normal base case, replace the more simplified sectoral calculations of the goods and services market module.

The goods and services market sits within a larger social accounting matrix that tracks financial flows among households, firms, and the government. The integrated economic model also allows computation of income distribution and poverty rates.

The Goods and Services Market

The Production Function: Basic Overview

 Cobb-Douglas production functions involving sector-specific technology or multifactor productivity (TEFF), capital (KS) and labor (LABS) provide potential value added (VADDP) in each sector, taking into account the level of capacity utilization (CAPUT), initially set exogenously (caputtar ). In a multi-sector model the functions require sectoral exponents for capital (CDALFS) and labor that, assuming constant returns to scale, sum to one within sectors.

Solow (1956) long ago recognized that the standard Cobb-Douglas production function with a constant scaling coefficient in front of the capital and labor terms was inadequate because the expansion of capital stock and labor supply leave a large portion of economic growth unexplained. It then became standard practice to represent an exogenously specified growth of technology term in front of the capital and labor terms as "disembodied" technological progress (Allen 1968: Chapter 13). Romer (1994) began to show the value of unpacking such a term and specifying its elements in the model, thereby endogenously representing this otherwise very large residual, which we can understand to represent the growth of multifactor productivity (MFP).

In IFs that total endogenous productivity growth factor (TEFF) is the accumulation over time (hence a stock like labor and capital) of annual values of growth in multifactor productivity (MFPGRO). There are many components contributing to growth of productivity, and there is a vast literature around them. See, for example, Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1999) for theoretical and empirical treatment of productivity drivers; also see Barro (1997) for empirical analysis (or McMahon 1999) for a focus on education.

In the development of IFs there was a fundamental philosophic choice to make. One option was to keep the multi-factor productivity function very simple, perhaps to restrict it to one or two key drivers, and to estimate the function as carefully as possible. Suggestions included focusing on the availability/price of energy and the growth in electronic networking and the knowledge society.

The second option was to develop a function that included many more factors known or strongly suspected to influence productivity and to attempt a more stylistic representation of the function, using empirical research to aid the effort as much as possible. The advantages of the second approach include creating a model that is much more responsive to a wide range of policy levers over the long term. The disadvantages include some inevitable complications with respect to overlap and redundancy of factor representation, as well as some considerable complexity of presentation.

Because IFs is a thinking tool and an extensively integrated multi-model system, the second approach was adopted, and the production function has become an element of the economic model that will be subject to regular revision and enhancement. IFs groups the many drivers of multifactor productivity into five categories, recognizing that even the categories overlap somewhat. The base category is one that represents core technological development and transfer elements of convergence theory, with less developed countries gradually catching up with more developed ones. The four other categories incorporate factors that can either retard or accelerate such convergence, transforming the overall formulation into one of conditional convergence.

The convergence base . The base rate of multifactor productivity growth (MFPRATE) is the sum of the growth rate for technological advance or knowledge creation of a technological leader in the global system (mfpleadr ) and a convergence premium (MFPPrem) that is specific to each country/region. The basic concept is that it can be easier for less developed countries to adopt existing technology than for leading countries to develop it (assuming some basic threshold of development has been crossed). The base rate for the leader remains an unexplained residual in the otherwise endogenous representation of MFP, but that has the value of making it available to model users to represent, if desired, technological cycles over time (e.g. Kondratief waves). The base also includes a correction term (MFPCor) that is initially set to the difference between empirical growth of MFP (calculated the first year as a residual between factor growth and output growth) and the sum of the technological leader and convergence premium terms. Over time, the correction term is phased out, but the four other terms (below) become key drivers of country-specific productivity. In fact, significant change in the other terms can either undercut the foundational convergence process or greatly augment it.

Human capital . This term has multiple components, including changes in educational spending as a portion of GDP, educational attainment of adults, and changes in health expenditure. For example, Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1999: 433) estimated that a 1.5% increase in government expenditures on education translates into approximately a 0.3% increase in annual economic growth.

Social capital . Similarly, social capital representation aggregates several components including economic freedom and absence of overt social conflict. Illustratively, the value of the parameter for economic freedom (elgref ) was estimated in a cross-sectional relationship of change in GDP level from 1985 to 1995 with the level of economic freedom. Similarly, Barro places great emphasis in his estimation work on the "rule of law".

Physical capital . In collaborative work with the IFs project, Robert Ayres correctly emphasized the close relationship between energy supply availability and economic growth. For instance, a rapid increase in world energy prices (WEP) essentially makes much capital stock less valuable. IFs uses world energy price relative to world energy prices in the previous year to compute an energy price term. The physical capital term also represents the extent of various types of infrastructure in a society.

Knowledge Capital . This fourth term includes changes in the R&D spending, computed from government spending (GDS) on R&D as a portion of total government spending (GOVCON) contribute to knowledge creation, notably in the more developed countries. Globerman (2000) reviewed empirical work on the private and social returns to R&D spending and found them to be in the 30-40% range; see also Griffith, Redding, and Van Reenen (2000). Many other factors undoubtedly contribute to superior knowledge development diffusion. This term represents especially the extent of economic integration with the global economy via trade.

All of the elements computed in the human, social, physical and knowledge capital terms are used in shaping economic productivity and growth rates of the model on a differential basis–that is, they are computed and evaluated relative to underlying "expected" patterns given overall economic development levels. Their actual levels can be above or below expected ones and they can therefore either add to or slow down the productivity growth rate. See the detailed equations of the production function for elaboration. <header><hgroup>

The Production Function: Detail

The core equation for the production function computes value added (VADD) from technology (TEFF), capital (KS), labor (LABS), and capacity utilization (CAPUT), with a time-constant scaling parameter (CDA) assuring that gross production is consistent with data the first year. GDP is, of course, the sum across sectors of valued added. Although the production function can serve all sectors of IFs, the parameters agon and enon act as switches; when their values are one, production in the agricultural and primary energy sectors, respectively, are determined in the larger, partial equilibrium models and the values then override this computation (see documentation on those models for detail).

$ VADDP_{r,s}=CDA_{r,s,t=1}*TEFF_{r,s}*CAPUT_{r,s}*KS_{r,s}^{CDALFS_{r,s}}*LABS_{r,s}^{(1-CDALFS_{r,s})} $

$ s=3,4...nsectr $ or $ s=1,2...nsectr $

where

$ CDA_{r,s,t=1}=\frac{VADDP_{r,s,t=1}}{(KS_{r,s,t-1})^{CDALFS_{r,s,t=1}}*(LABS_{r,s,t=1})^{(1-CDALFS_{r,s,t=1})}} $

$ CAPUT_{r,s,t=1}=\mathbf{caputtar} $

Other topics in our documentation explain the dynamics underlying change in capital stock (through investment and depreciation) and labor supply (through demographic change and participation patterns). The rest of this topic will focus on the computation of the elements that go into the MFP or technology term (TEFF), working our way progressively deeper into their determinants.

At the most basic level the stock term is simply an accumulation of the annual increments in MFP. 

$ TEFF_{r,s}=TEFF_{r,s,t-1}*(1+MFPGRO_{r,s}) $; where  $ TEFF_{r,s,t=1}= $

The annual growth in MFP (MFPGRO) consists of a base rate linked to systemic technology advance and convergence (MFPRATE) plus four terms that affect MFP growth over time as a result of human, social, physical, and knowledge capital. 

$ MFPGRO_{r,s}=MFPRATE_{r,s}+MPFHC_{r,s}+MFPSC_{r,s}+MFPPC_{r,s}+MFPKN $

Each of the following subsections elaborates one of the five terms.

Annual Base Technology Growth in MFP

The base rate related to technology or other factors unexplained by the four capital terms is anchored by an exogenous specification of the sector-specific rate of advance in the systemic leader’s technology (mfpleadr ); the leader is assumed to be the United States. (The rate in the leader's ICT sector gradually convergences over time to that of the service sector.) On top of that is an endogenously computed premium computed for convergence of each country/region (MFPPrem), a term that is a function of GDP per capita at PPP, the function for which posits an inverted-V shape with the greatest potential for technological convergence to the leader among middle-income countries. In this calculation there needs to be a correction factor (MFPCor), computed to assure that the actual rate of this growth is consistent with the actual amount of growth for a country/region (MFPGRO) that is unexplained by capital and labor growth in the first model run year. That correction factor converges to 0 over the number of years specified by mfpconv . This convergence assumption has significant implications for model behavior because it tends to slow down growth in countries (like China) that have had a burst of growth beyond that which the rates of the leader and the catch-up factor would lead us to anticipate and to speed up growth in countries (like the transition states of Central Europe) that have suffered a reduction similarly unexpected by the basic formulation.

$ MFPRATE_{r,s}=\mathbf{mfpleadr}_{s}+MFPrem_{r}+MFPCor_{r,s}+MFPGloCor_{t=1}+\mathbf{mfpbasgr}+\mathbf{mfpbasinc}*zy+\mathbf{mfpadd}_{r} $

where

$ MFPPrem_{r}=Func(GDPPCP_{r}) $

$ MFPCor_{r,s,t=1}=MFPGRO_{r,s,t=1}-MFPRATE_{r,s,t=1} $and

$ MFPCor_{r,s,t}=(ConvergeOverTime(MFPCor_{r,s,t=1},0,\mathbf{mfpconv}) $

$ MFPGloCor_{t=1}=\sum_{r=1}^{R}\sum_{s=1}^{S}MFPCor_{r,s,t=1}*VADD_{r,s,t=1}*VADD_{r,s,t=1}/\sum_{r=1}^{R}\sum_{s=1}^{S}VADD_{r,s,t=1} $

It is possible for the regionally and sectorally specific MFP correction terms (MFPCOR) to still leave a small discrepancy between the global economic growth in the data and the initial growth rate in the model. To avoid this, we also compute a global correction factor (MFPGloCor) as the region/country and value added weighted sum of the individual country-sector terms divided by the global and regional sums of value added.

In addition to the basic technology terms and the correction factors, there are three parameters in the MFPRATE equation (with zero values as the default) that allow the model user much control over assumptions of technological advance. The first is basic parameter (mfpbasgr ) that allows a global growth increment or decrement; the second is a parameter (mfpbasinc ) that allows either a constant rise or slowing of growth rate globally, year by year, where zy is the count of the model run years across time; finally is a frequently-used parameter (mfpadd ) allowing flexible intervention for any country/region.

Driver Cluster 1: Human Capital

The general logic of each the four driver clusters around human, social, physical, and knowledge capital is the same. Each cluster aggregates several variables that generally contribute to productivity. For each variable, such as average years of adult education in the human capital cluster, there is an expected value and an actual value. It is the difference between actual and expected values that gives rise to a positive or negative contribution to productivity and growth. Most expected values are identified in a relationship with GDP per capita at PPP.

That is, there is a tendency for most developmentally supportive variables to advance in a rough relationship with each other and with GDP per capita (Kuznets 1959 and 1966; Chenery and Syrquin 1975; Syrquin and Chenery 1989; Sachs 2005). To the degree that they do, such advance can be understood to be consistent also with the overall technological advance of the country. If, however, a variables such as years of formal education attained by adults exceeds the typical or expected value for a country at a given level of GDP per capita, we can expect that variable to add something more to productivity. Similarly, falling behind the expected value could retard productivity advance. To illustrate and emphasize this point, even a country for which adult education levels advance could find that education is not keeping up with the advance in other developmental variables including GDP per capita and find that its education levels move from contributing to productivity enhancement to decrementing that productivity enhancement.

In the human capital cluster there are six variables that add to or subtract from the human capital (MFPHC) term: the educational spending contribution (EdExpContrib), the years of adult education contribution (EdYearsContribub), the boost from life expectancy years (LifExpEdYrsBoost) assumed to generate (via mfpedlifexp ) extra years of education, the stunting contribution (StuntContrib) related to undernutrition of children, the disability contribution (DisabContrib) related to morbidity from the health model, and vocational education contribution (edVoccontrib) resulting from growth (or decline) in vocational share of lower and upper secondary enrollment,. The first five of these six drivers have a similar formulation while the formulation for vocational education is slightly different. The first five, as computed in IFs often as a result of extended formulations and even other models of system (as with life expectancy, computed in the health model) are compared with an expected value. In the case of disability, the expected value is set to the world average level (WorldDisavg), but all other expected values (EdExpComp, EdYrsComp, LifExpComp, and StuntingComp) are computed as functions of GDP per capita at PPP. As the provision of vocational education does not follow any common pattern or trend and is rather a matter of policy choices made (or will be made) by the particular country, it was not possible to calculate an expected value for this variable We have instead computed the vocational education contribution from changes in vocational share over time with appropriate moving averages to capture the lag required in materializing such contribution and to smooth out the contribution over time. (Note: In the base case of the model, vocational shares do not change and as such EdVocContrib is zero).

In each case a parameter drawn from study of the literature and/or our own analysis converts the difference between actual and expected into a positive or negative contribution to MFP. (Because of the recursive structure of IFs, some terms rely on variables from the previous time step, estimated from the current time step with a correction factor based on initial GDP growth.)

$ MFPHC_{r}=EdExpContrib_{r}+EdYrsContrib_{r}+LifExpEdYrsBoost_{r}+StuntContrib_{r}+DisabContrib_{r}+edVocContrib_{r} $

where

$ EdExpContrib_{r}=(\frac{GDS_{r,s=EDUC,t-1}*(1+IGDPRCor_{r})}{GDP_{r,t-1}*(1+IGDPRCor_{r})}*100-EdExpComp_{r})*\mathbf{mfpedspn} $

$ EdYrsContrib_{r}=(EDYRSAG15_{r,t-1}-EdYrsComp_{r})*\mathbf{mfpedyrs} $

$ LifExpEdYrsBoost_{r}=(Amin(LIFEXP_{r,t-1},SLifExpSlow_{r}+2)-LifExpComp_{r})*\mathbf{mfpedlifexp}*\mathbf{mfpedyrs} $

$ StuntContrib_{r}=(HLSTUNT_{r,t-1}-StuntingComp_{r})*\mathbf{mfpstunt} $

$ DisabContrib_{r}=(Amin(0.17,\frac{SumHlYLDWork_{r}}{Amax(0.001,POPWORKING_{r})})-WorldDisAvg)*\mathbf{mfphlyld} $

$ edVocContrib_{r,t}=f(EDSECLOWRVOC_{r,t-1}, EDSECLOWRVOC_{r,t-2}, EDSECUPPRVOC_{r,t-1}, EDSECUPPRVOC_{r,t-2}) $

$ edVocContrib_{r}=(0.9*edVocContrib_{r,t-1}+0.1*edVocContrib_{r,t})*\mathbf{mfpedvoc} $

where

Vocational contribution for lower secondary is calculated as:

$ eSecLowrVoc_{r,t}=0.9*eSecLowrVoc_{r,t-1}+0.1*EDSECLOWRVOC_{r,total,t-1} $

$ edVocSecLowrContrib_{r}=EDSECLOWRVOC_{r,total,t-1}-eSecLowrVoc_{r} $

A similar calculation is done for upper secondary vocational and the two are averaged as shown below:

$ edVocContrib_{r}=(edVocSecLowrContrib_{r}+edVocSecLowrContrib_{r})/2 $

Driver Cluster 2: Social Capital

The logic of comparison of actual with expected values is the same as that described above for human capital in the case of the six factors that contribute to social capital: economic freedom as in the Fraser Institute measure (EconFreeContrib), government effectiveness as in the World Bank measure (GovtEffContrib), corruption as in the Transparency International measure (CorruptContrib), democracy as in the Polity project measure (DemocPolicyContrib), freedom as in the Freedom House measure (FreedomContrib), and conflict as in the IFs project's own measure tied in turn to the work of the Political Instability Task Force (ConflictContrib). In each case other than that for conflict, the expected values (EconFreeComp, GovEffectComp, CorruptComp, DemocPolityComp, and FreeComp) are computed from functions with GDP per capita at PPP. In the case of conflict, the expected value is set at the initial year's value (and the comparison is reversed because lower conflict values contribute positively to MFP).

$ MFPSC_{r}=EconFreeContrib_{r}+GovtEffContrib_{r}+CorruptComp_{r}+DemocPolityContrib_{r}+FreedomContrib_{r}+ConflictContrib_{r} $

where

$ EconFreeContrib_{r}=(ECONFREE_{r,t-1}-EconFreeComp_{r})*\mathbf{mfpefree} $

$ GovtEffectContrib_{r}=(GovEffect_{r,t-1}-GovEffectComp_{r})*\mathbf{mfpgoveff} $

$ CorruptContrib_{r}=(GOVCORRUPT_{r,t-1}-CorruptComp_{r})*\mathbf{mfpgovcor} $

$ DemocPolityContrib_{r}=(DemcPolity_{r,t-1}-DemoPolityComp_{r})*\mathbf{mfpdemoc} $

$ FreedomContrib_{r}=(FREEDOM_{r,t-1}-FreeComp_{r})*\mathbf{mfpfree} $

$ ConflictContrib_{r}=(GOVINDSECRI_{r,t=1}-GOVINDSECR_{r,t})*\mathbf{mfpconflict} $

Driver Cluster 3: Physical Capital

The logic of the physical capital cluster is again parallel to that of the human and social capital clusters and involves the comparison of an actual (that is, IFs computed) with an expected value. The formulation for MFPPC can actually take several forms depending on the value of a switching parameter (inframfpsw ) but the standard form involves four contributions, from traditional infrastructure (InfraTradContrib), ICT infrastructure (InfraICTContrib), other infrastructure spending level (InfOthSpenContrib), and the price of energy (EnPriceTerm). The last term is included because higher prices of energy can make some forms of capital plant no longer efficient or productive.

In the case of this cluster only the expected value of the traditional infrastructure index (InfraIndTradComp) and the expected value of other infrastructure spending (InfraOthSpendComp) are computed as most other cluster elements are, namely as a function of GDP per capita at PPP. In the case of the ICT index contribution, the technology has been evolving so rapidly that there is not really a basis for an expected value with some stability over time. Instead the contribution from ICT is computed in terms of a moving average value of change over time, such that faster rates of change contribute more to MFP as the moving average expected value lags further behind the actual. In the case of the energy price term, the "expected" value is set equal to the energy price in the first year of the model run. As with other clusters and the variables in them, a single parameter links the discrepancy between actual and expected values to MFP.

$ MFPPC_{r}=InfraTradContrib_{r}+InfraICTContrib_{r}+InfOthSpndContrib_{r}+EnPriceTerm_{r,t-1} $

where

$ InfraTradContrib_{r}=(INFRAINDTRAD_{r,t-1}-InfraIndTradComp_{r})*\mathbf{mfpinfraindtrad} $

$ InfraICTContrib_{r}=(0.8*IndICTIndChange_{r,t-1}+0.2*IndICTIndChange_{r,t})*\mathbf{mfpinfraindict} $

where

$ IndICTIndChange_{r}=InfraIndICT_{r,t-1}-InfraIndICT_{r,t-2} $

$ InfraOthSpndContrib_{r}=(\frac{GDS_{r,s=InfraOther,t-1}*(1+IGDPRCor_{r})}{GDP_{r,t-1}*(1+IGDPRCor_{r})}*100-INFRAOthSpndComp_{r})*\mathbf{mfpinfrothspnd} $

$ PhysicalCapitalTerm_{r,s}=EnPriceTerm_{t-1} $

$ EnPriceTerm_{t-1}=(\frac{WEP_{t-1}-WEP_{t=1}}{WEP_{t=1}})*\mathbf{mfpenpri} $

Driver Cluster 4: Knowledge Capital

Following the pattern of other MFP driver clusters, the one for knowledge accumulation includes terms that compare actual model and typical or expected values and use parameters to translate the differences into increments or decrements of MFP. In this case the three terms represent R&D spending (RDExpContrib), economic integration via trade with the rest of the world (EIntContrib) and the share of science and engineering among all tertiary degrees earned (EdTerSciContrib). In the first and third case the expected value (RDExpComp; EdTerGRSciEnComp) is a function of GDP per capita at PPP. In the second instance, there is no clear relationship between extent of economic integration and GDP per capita, so the model compares a moving average of trade openness (exports plus imports as a percentage of GDP) with the initial value of openness (because trade is computed later in the computational sequence for each year, the values of trade variables lag one year behind those of the production function). Given the extreme global range of trade openness, the elasticity term itself in this relationship is variable, with values decreasing when initial openness is greater (that is, countries that start with less openness gain more from the same percentage point increases in it).

$ KnowledgeTerm_{r,s}=RDExpContrib_{r}+EIntContrib_{r}+EdTerSciContrib_{r} $

where

$ RDExpContrib_{r}=(RANDEXP_{r,t-1}-RDExpComp)*\mathbf{mfprandd} $

$ EIntContrib_{r}=(TradeTermMA_{r,t-1}-TradeTerm_{r,t=1})/10*ElasTerm_{r} $

where

$ TradeTerm_{r}=\frac{X_{r}+M_{r}}{GDP_{r}}*100 $

$ TradeTermMA_{r}=0.8*TradeTermMA_{r,t-1}+0.2*TradeTerm_{r,t-1} $

$ ElasTerm_{r}=Amax(0.1*\mathbf{mfpeconint},Amin(2*\mathbf{mfpeconint},\mathbf{mfpeconint}*(1+\frac{50-TradeTerm_{r,t=1}}{50}))) $

$ EdTerSciContrib_{r}=(EDTERGRSCIEN_{r,t-1}*EDTERGRATE_{r,t-1}/100-EdTerGrSciEnComp)*\mathbf{mfpedscien} $

Issues Concerning Parameterization and Interaction Effects

Although our approach to calculation of MFP creatively connects developments in many other models in the IFs system to it, parameterization of the effects individually and in interaction is complicated and uncertain. Hughes (2005) documented the original creation of the structure and its parameterization based on existing literature.

One of the concerns with this approach is the possibility of double counting of effects from the large number of variables fed into the MFP calculations. In general the project has dealt in part with this by selecting conservative values for the parameters when studies indicate possible ranges of contribution of the variables to productivity and/or growth. Another concern is that a very large or extreme advance by one or a small subset of variables could have inappropriately large impacts of productivity given the fundamental conceptual foundation of the approach in the notion that development involves widespread and reinforcing structural changes across many variables. In order to limit this possibility, we have created an algorithmic function (MFPContribAdj) to adjust the multiple MFP contributions and dampen especially high positive or negative contributions of the four cluster terms (MFPHC, MFPSC, MFPPC, and MFPKN). 

The Relationship of Physical Models to the Economic Model

IFs normally does not use the economic model's equations representing MFP and production for the first two economic sectors, because the agriculture and energy models provide gross production for them (unless those sectors are disconnected from economics using the agon and/or enon parameters). Instead, the two physical models provide gross production, translated to value terms, back to the economic model. See Section 3.2.3 for discussion of gross production.

In addition to this impact of the physical models on the economic model, there is one more of importance. Physical shortages on energy may constrain actual value added in each sector (VADD) relative to potential production. Economists typically do not accept such shortages as a real world phenomenon because (at least in theory) prices rise to clear markets; yet periods like the 1970s when governments intervened in those markets, such shortages do appear and they can in some IFs scenarios. In those situations, IFs assumes that energy shortages (ENSHO), as a portion of domestic energy demand (ENDEM) and export commitments (ENX) lower actual production in all sectors through a physical shortage multiplier factor (SHOMF). A parameter/switch (squeeze ) controls this linkage and can turn it off.

$ VADD_{r,s}=VADDP_{r,s}*(1-ShoMF_{r})*(\frac{MKAV_{s=manuf}}{MKAV_{s=manuf,t=1}})^{prodme} $

where

$ ShoMF=\frac{ENSHO_{r}}{ENDEM_{r}+ENX_{r}}*\mathbf{squeez} $

In addition, the translation of potential into actual production depends on the imports of manufactured goods (MKAV), which serve as a proxy for both availability of intermediate goods and for technological imports. A parameter (PRODME) also controls this relationship.

Although the IFs model represents prices in real terms (no monetary sector and no inflation), there are relative sectoral price changes (PRI). Some of those can be quite dramatic over time, especially in the agricultural and energy sectors where the equilibration of physical representations of supply and demand can swing those prices. Such relative price swings can, in the real world, give added drag or boost to the value added in certain sectors and for economies as a whole. To represent this we compute a relative-price adjusted version of value added (VADDRPA), which is the normal value added weighted by world sectoral prices (WP); the prices are lagged a year because of the recursive model structure.

$ VADDRPA_{r,s}=VADD_{r,s}*WP_{s,t-1} $

Gross Production and Intersectoral Flows

Given value added in each sector it is possible using an exogenously provided input/output matrix (A) to determine the level of gross production in each sector. We will see below, however, that the A-matrix is actually computed as a function of GDP per capita—the model interpolates among multiple A-matrices for various levels of GDP per capita in a procedure originally developed for the GLOBUS model (Hughes 1987).

$ ZS_{r,s}=\frac{VADD_{r,s}}{1-\Sigma^{Row}A_{row,column=s}} $

Given gross production and the A-matrix we can compute intersectoral flows (INTS).

$ INTS_{row,column=s}=ZS_{r,s}*A_{row,column=s} $

Production available for final demand (PFD) is the residual of gross production minus the sum delivered to all columns.

$ PFD_{r,s}=ZS_{r,s}-\sum^{Column}INTS_{row=s,column} $

GDP per capita-linked generic A-matrices are created in the pre-processor of IFs. To build them the IFs project turned to the IO matrices collected in the Global Trade Analysis Project. That database includes extensive data, including IO matrices, for 127 regions/individual countries across 57 sectors in GTAP 8 (every version tends to increase geographic coverage). With origins in 1992 of the now global project at the agricultural economics department of Purdue, GTAP heavily represents agricultural sectors. Narayanan, Aguilar and McDougall (2012) documented GTAP 8 (see also earlier versions including Dimaranan and McDougall (2002) for GTAP 5).

The pre-processor of IFs (Hughes and Irfan 2006) processes the IO matrices of GTAP to create those needed by IFs. One aspect of that involves collapsing the sectors to those of IFs (currently 6) using a concordance table. Even more importantly, however, the pre-processor generates from the most recent GTAP files within IFs a set of nine generic IO matrices to represent the average technical coefficient pattern of countries at different levels of GDP per capita. The generic matrices are calculated as unweighted averages of matrices for all countries with GDPs per capita in categories established by lower-end breakpoints of $0, $175, $375, $750, $1,500, $3,000, $6,000, $12,000, and $24,000.

The assumption behind the generic IO matrices is that countries at different GDP per capita levels typically use different types of technology. The resultant IO matrices bear this out in ways that seem intuitively plausible. For example, Tables 3.1 and 3.2 show (using earlier data from GTAP 5) the technical coefficient matrices for extreme levels of GDP/capita, below $100 and above $24,000, respectively. Note, for instance, how much lower a share of manufactures goes into the agricultural sector in the richest countries relative to the poorest, and how much more of the IC sector goes back into the IC sector in richer countries.

Table 3.1 Generic IO Matrix for Countries with GDP/Capita Below $100

 

AG

RM

PE

MN

SR

IC

AG Sector

0.2624

0.0112

0.0008

0.0846

0.0194

0.0014

RM Sector

0.0041

0.0425

0.1571

0.0499

0.0087

0.0418

PE Sector

0.0048

0.2158

0.0265

0.0735

0.0119

0.0362

MN Sector

0.0522

0.0540

0.0687

0.1652

0.0774

0.0780

SR Sector

0.1847

0.2260

0.2177

0.1797

0.1721

0.1808

IC Sector

0.0026

0.0090

0.0040

0.0058

0.0105

0.0271

 

Table 3.2 Generic IO Matrix for Countries with GDP/Capita Above $24,000

 

AG

RM

PE

MN

SR

IC

AG Sector

0.3483

0.0005

0.0017

0.0133

0.0107

0.0004

RM Sector

0.0132

0.0366

0.1385

0.0186

0.0063

0.0067

PE Sector

0.0141

0.2660

0.0118

0.0823

0.0040

0.0287

MN Sector

0.0645

0.0614

0.0822

0.1812

0.0670

0.0856

SR Sector

0.1586

0.1786

0.1533

0.2004

0.2399

0.1632

IC Sector

0.0061

0.0093

0.0113

0.0156

0.0169

0.0966

 

These generic matrices are used for two purposes. First, they are used for estimating values for countries of IFs that are NOT in the GTAP data set. Second, they are used in the actual dynamic calculations of the model. As countries rise in GDP/capita, interpolations between matrices above and below their level allow us to gradually change the matrix representing each country.

GTAP also provides data on return to four factors of production in each sector: land, unskilled labor, skilled labor, and capital. These returns represent value added and are very important data for the value added blocks of the SAM. The pre-processor also collapses these values into the (six) sectors of IFs and computes generic shares of the factors in value added by GDP per capita category, using the same unweighted average technique used for the IO coefficients. Once again the generic value-added shares are used both to fill country holes in the GTAP data set and to provide a basis for dynamically representing changes in those shares as countries develop.

Table 3.3 Generic Returns to Labor for Countries Below GDP/Capita $100

 

AG

RM

PE

MN

SR

IC

Unskilled

0.2873

0.1544

0.1763

0.1378

0.2878

0.1721

Skilled

0.0063

0.0264

0.0384

0.0234

0.1325

0.1132

 

Table 3.4 Generic Returns to Labor for Countries Above GDP/Capita $24,000

 

AG

RM

PE

MN

SR

IC

Unskilled

0.1795

0.2146

0.0854

0.2159

0.2074

0.2054

Skilled

0.0386

0.0842

0.0952

0.1060

0.1715

0.1618

 

The changes across the levels of GDP/capita appear reasonable. Note, for instance, the general shift of return to skilled from unskilled labor and the increase in returns to labor in total for the manufacturing and ICT sectors (at the expense of capital and other inputs).

The equations for value added and income in household categories can be found in the discussion of households as agents. Although the GTAP data by no means provide everything that was needed for the generation of universal SAMs, the project is aware of the utility of SAMs (Brockmeier and Arndt 2002) and provided several primary data inputs that serve our purposes.

Further, the GTAP data and the GDP per capita threshold approach is used in the pre-processor to compute a generic table for labor demand coefficients by sector, distinguishing skilled and unskilled labor. These are stored in the IOLaborCoefs table of IFs.mdb and are available for the computation of labor demand in the economic model. 

Labor Supply

Labor supply (LAB) is a function of population, depending on a labor force participation rate (LAPOPR). In earlier versions of IFs that participation rate was an exogenous parameter. It has now been decomposed into three elements: (1) the share of the population in the traditional working ages between 15 and 65, (2) the retirement age, and (3) the participation rate of women.

At one time we computed the share of population in the traditional working ages as a ratio of the size of the population in that age category (POP15TO65) and population (POP).

$ Pop15to65Ratio_{r}=\frac{POP15TO65_{r}}{POP_{r}} $

Although the name of the variable has not been changed yet, the formulation has now been changed in order to represent variable ages of entry into the work force (workageentry ) and retirement age (workageretire ) across countries and time. Those parameters are used to compute an actual working aged population (POPWORKING) or potential labor force in an algorithm across population age categories in the population model.

$ Pop15to65Ratio_{r}=\frac{POPWORKING_{r}}{POP_{r}} $

where

$ POPWORKING_{r}=F(AgeDst_{c,r},\mathbf{workageentry}_{r},\mathbf{workageretire}_{r}) $

The participation of women in the work force (FEMSHRLAB) as a share of the total labor force is assumed to grow over time with an exogenous parameter based on past experience (femshrgr ); the representation of women as a share of the labor force rather than in terms of percentage points of their participation somewhat complicates the equations below. The growth in labor-force share is modified by a multiplier (FemShrLabMul) that introduces saturation as female participation rates approach a target (FemShrTar). The model user can modify that target, normally between 50 and 60% via an exogenous parameter (labfemshrm ).

$ FEMSHRLAB_r=FEMSHRLAB_{r,t=1}+\mathbf{femshrgr}*FemShrLabMul_{r} $

where

$ FemShrLabMul_r=\frac{FemShrTar_r-FEMSHRLAB_{r,t-1}}{FemShrTar_r-FEMSHRLAB_{r,t=1}} $

$ FemShrTar_r=Amin(60,Amin(50,FEMSHRLAB_{r,t=1}+20)*\mathbf{labfemshrm}_e) $

Given the three drivers of labor force participation rates (LAPOPR) it is possible to compute it relative to the rate in the first year:

$ LAPOPR_r=(LAPOPR_{r,t=1}+\frac{FEMSHRLAB_r-FEMSHRLAB_{r,t=1}}{100}*\frac{FEMSHRLAB_{r,t=1}}{100})*\frac{Pop15to65Ratio_r}{Pop15to65Ratio_{r,t=1}}*\mathbf{labretagem}_r*\mathbf{lapoprm}_r $

Change in the retirement age can be reflected in the above equation via a multiplicative parameter (labretagem ), but it does not give the precision of control that workageretire does and is no longer recommended for use. The multiplier on participation rate (lapoprm ) is, however, a useful scenario intervention point.

The product of participation rate and population provides the total labor pool (LAB).

$ LAB_r=POP_{r,t}*LAPOPR_r $

The total labor pool can be divided into subcomponents in two different ways. First, labor is spread across production sectors (LABS). Second, it is differentiated by household type in to skilled and unskilled labor (LABSUP).

Labor Supply by Sector

Labor by sector of the economy (LABS) is a share of the total labor force (LAB) minus unemployment calculated at an exogenous unemployment rate (UNEMPR). The sectoral share is calculated in a function that estimates the labor demand for each unit of value added (VADD) at given levels of GDP per capita (GDPPC).

$ LABS_{r,s}=\frac{LAB_r*(1-\mathbf{unempr}_r)*\Sigma^HLaborF_{r,s}}{\Sigma^S\Sigma^HLaborF_{r,s}} $

where

$ LaborF_{r,s}=AnalFunc(GDPPC_r,VADD_{r,s}) $

Labor Supply by Household Skill Category

Labor by household type (LABSUP) is determined by calculation of the percentage that comes from skilled households (PerSkilled). At the core of that calculation of percent skilled is an analytical function with GDP per capita at PPP (GDPPCP). But the analytical function is fundamentally tied to conditions that prevail in the contemporary era (as captured by the GTAP data on which it is based). We know that education levels have been increasing, even to the extent of involving some credential inflation. Thus the percentage of the labor force considered skilled is likely to increase faster than the function indicates. Thus it is modified by a skilled labor adjustment factor (LabSupSkiAdj) that takes into account the difference between the actual extent of education among adults over 15 (EDYEARS15) and the expected level and translated that into a boost or reduction in the percentage skilled in the same manner that differences between actual and expected years affect MFP in the production function. The YearsEdDiff term simply maintains the difference by country/region of the initial (year 2) difference between the expected years from the function and the actual years of education.

$ LABSUP_{r,h=Skilled}=LAB_r*\frac{PerSkilled}{100} $

where

$ PerSkilled=AnalFunc(GDPPCP_r)*(1+LabSupSkiAdj) $

$ LabSupSkiAdj=\frac{EDYEARS15_r-YearsEdExp}{YearsEd}*0.3 $

and

$ YearsEd=AnalFunc(GDPPCP_r) $

$ YearsEdDiff_r=EDYRSAG15_{r,t=2}-YearsEd_{t=2} $

$ YearsEdExp=YearsEd+YearsEdDiff_r $

The unskilled labor is computed as a residual.

$ LABSUP_{r,h=UnSkilled}=LAB_r-LABSUP_{r,h=Skilled} $

Capital-Labor Shares

The Cobb-Douglas exponent (CDALF) of the production function is known to change over long time periods, giving somewhat less weight to capital as an economy becomes more capital intensive (see, for instance, Thirlwall 1977: chapter 2). The GTAP project data again provided the basis for an estimation of this relationship.

That function, in combination with data from Thirlwall and others on sectoral differences in capital share, allow the computation of sectoral capital shares (CDAlfS), normalized so as to generate CDALF for the total economy. A parameter (salpha ) represents a generic pattern of capital share variation across production sectors.

$ CDALF_r=AnalFunc(GDPPCP_r) $

$ CDAlfS_{r,s}=Normalization(CDALF_r,saplha_s) $

GDP at MER and PPP and Relative-price Adjusted GDP

Gross regional or domestic product (GDP) is the sum of value added across sectors, which would also equal the sum of production for final demand across sectors.

$ GDP_r=\sum^SVADD_{r,s} $

The GDP per capita (GDPPC) and the regional economic growth rate (GDPR) follow easily.

$ GDPPC_r=\frac{GDP_r}{POP_r} $

$ GDPR_r=\frac{GDP_r-GDP_{r,t-1}}{GDP_{r,t-1}} $

The basic GDP figures for the model are represented in dollars at official exchange rate values. It is important, however, to estimate the value of GDP and GDPPC at purchasing power parity levels as well (GDPP and GDPPCP). To do that we need to compute a purchasing power parity conversion value (PPPConV). Data sources provide the initial conversion value. IFs uses an analytic function that relates GDP per capita at MER to that at PPP to compute change in the conversion value over time.

The initial condition for the conversion ratio comes from data values for the GDP per capita at PPP and MER. Over time, the conversion ratio (which can be considerably above 1 for developing countries) erodes. The annual erosion is the difference between the previous year's value and a product of two terms: (1) an initial ratio that controls for any difference between the actual GDP per capita at PPP and the value produced by the function relating it to GDP per capita at MER (this ratio should not normally be very different from 1); (2) the current conversion ratio, which uses the potential GDP per capita (actual GDP per capita having not yet been computed) to feed the analytical function.

$ GDPP_r=GDP_r*PPPConV_r $

$ GDPPCP_r=GDPPC_r*PPPConV_r $

where

$ PPPConV_{r,t=1}=\frac{GDPPCP_{r,t=1}}{GDPPC_{r,t=1}} $

$ PPPConV_{r,t}=PPPConV_{r,t-1}-(PPPConV_{r,t-1}-(FunctionRatioInitial_{r,t=1}*ConversionRatioCurrent_{r,t})) $

$ FunctionRatioInitial_{r,t=1}=\frac{GDPPCP_{r,t=1}}{AnalFunc(GDPPC_{r,t=1}} $

$ ConversionRatioCurrent_{r,t}=\frac{AnalFunc(GDPPOTPC_{r,t})}{GDPPOTPC_{r,t}} $

Although the IFs model represents prices in real terms (no monetary sector and inflation), there are relative sectoral price changes and a separate section of the documentation describes the computation of a relative-price adjusted value added (RPA). The sum of those can also produce a relative-price adjusted GDP (GDPRPA). The utility of this variable can be seen, for instance, in countries, like Saudi Arabia, that are heavily dependent on energy exports. Large swings in the relative price of the energy sector can dramatically affect the relative-price adjusted GDP and we therefore carry this variable forward from the goods and services market into the more encompassing social accounting matrix representation.

$ GDPRPA_r=\sum^SVADDRPA_{r,s} $

Trade

</hgroup></header> Imports and exports respond to regional prices (PRI) relative to those elsewhere. As a measure of prices elsewhere, IFs uses a world average price (WP), weighted by regional gross production and adjusted by the exchange rate (EXRATE).

$ WP_s=\frac{\Sigma^R(PRI_{r,s,t-1}*EXRATE_r*ZS_{r,s})}{\Sigma^RZS_{r,s}} $

The computation uses lagged prices because at this point the recursive equation system has not yet computed current prices.

Exports are responsive to both changes in production and changes in prices via respective elasticities. On the production side we begin by computing an export base (XBASE). It is initial exports (XS) plus some portion (XKAV) of growth in production, represented by potential gross sectoral production (ZSP). Representing a moving average of incremental production that is exported helps maintain global balance and stable behavior in long-term forecasting. The exported portion is modified over time in response to two elasticities. The first is a fairly standard elasticity of exports with income/production growth (elasxinc ). The second is an export shift parameter that one would normally use to represent scenarios about export promotion or constraint.

$ XBASE_{r,s}=(XS_{r,s,t-1}+(ZSP_{r,s}-ZSP_{r,s,t-1})*XKAV_{r,s}*\mathbf{elasxinc}_r)*(1+\mathbf{xshift}_r) $

Given the export base, export capacity (XC) responds to the difference between local and global prices using an elasticity of trade with prices (elastrpr ). In addition we use two parameters (first order and second order) to pursue dynamically a global trade balance over time (elprx1 and elprx2 ). You may wish more detail on the adjustment mechanism.

$ XC_{r,s}=XBASE_{r,s}*(1+(\frac{PRI_{r,s,t-1}*EXRATE_r-WP_s}{WP_s}))^{elxpr1}*(1+(\frac{PRI_{r,s,t-1}*EXRATE_r-WP_s}{WP_s}-\frac{PRI_{r,s,t-2}*EXRATE_{r,t-1}-WP_{r,t-1}}{WP_{r,t-1}}*\mathbf{elastrpr}_s))^{elxpr2} $

Import capacities or demands (MD) are almost exactly analogous. Whereas exports are tied to production, however, imports are tied to a demand base (DBASE) made up of final demands plus gross sectoral production potential (ZSP).

$ DBASE_{r,s}=CS_{r,s}+GS_{r,s}+INVS_{r,s}+ZSP_{r,s} $

Imports are responsive to both changes in income and changes in prices and respective elasticities. We use the demand base as the basis for the income term. Specifically, we create a basic import level (MBASE) that grows with the demand base, responsive to an income elasticity parameter for imports (elasminc ).

$ MBASE_{r,s}=MS_{r,s,t-1}+(DBASE_{r,s}-DBASE_{r,s,t-1})*MKAV_{r,s}*\mathbf{elasminc}_r $

A moving average for imports (MKAV) as a portion of changes in the demand base helps maintain global balance and stable behavior over the long-term.

Given this income responsive import base, regional prices relative to global ones (again with first and second order terms), an elasticity of imports with prices (elastrpr ), and parameters for dynamic change of imports (elprm1 and elprm2 ) largely determine import demands. One last factor, however, is a domestic protection multiplier (protecm ), which can cause the import price (MPRIC) to rise or fall relative to the world price.

$ MD_{r,s}=MBASE_{r,s}*(1+(\frac{PRI_{r,s,t-1}*EXRATE_r-MPRIC_{r,s}}{MPRIC_{r,s}}*\mathbf{elastrpr}_s))^{elmpr1}*(1+(\frac{PRI_{r,s,t-1}*EXRATE_r-MPRIC_{r,s}}{MPRIC_{r,s}}-\frac{PRI_{r,s,t-2}*EXRATE_{r,t-1}-MPRIC_{r,s,t-1}}{MPRIC_{r,s,t-1}}*\mathbf{elastrpr}_s))^{elmpr2} $

where

$ MPRIC_{r,s}=WP_{s}*\mathbf{protecm}_r $

World export capacity (WXC) and world import demand (WMD) are simply sums across regions.

$ WXC_s=\sum^RXC_{r,s} $

$ WMD_s=\sum^RMD_{r,s} $

These will always be somewhat different. Actual world trade (WT) is the average of the two.

$ WT_s=\frac{WXC_s+WMD_s}{2} $

We are now able to compute actual sectoral exports (XS) and imports (MS), normalizing the capacity for exports and the demand for imports to the actual world trade.

$ XS_{r,s}=WT_s\frac{XC_{r,s}}{WXC_s} $

$ MS_{r,s}=WT_s\frac{MD_{r,s}}{WMD_s} $

We can now update the moving average export (XKAV) and import (MKAV) propensities for the next cycle. This requires historical weights (xhw and mhw ) for exports (XHW) and imports (MHW).

$ XKAV_{r,s,t+1}=XKAV_{r,s}*\mathbf{xhw}+(1-\mathbf{xhw})*\frac{XS_{r,s}}{ZSP_{r,s}} $

$ MKAV_{r,s,t+1}=MKAV_{r,s}*\mathbf{mhw}+(1-\mathbf{mhw})*\frac{MS_{r,s}}{DBASE_{r,s}} $

The above equations are necessary only for three of the five economic sectors. The agriculture and energy models compute trade in those sectors separately. Given the computation of sectoral exports and imports for all sectors (in this or other models), it is possible to compute total exports (X) and imports (M).

$ X_r=\sum^SXS_{r,s} $

$ M_r=\sum^SMS_{{r,s}_s} $

IFs also computes these in a "relative-priced adjusted" form, multiplying the real sectoral values by global prices. Why is this important? If, for example, a country were highly dependent on energy exports and the price of energy (from the energy model) doubled relative to other prices, failure to adjust trade for prices would understand the country’s trade balance. It is the relative price-adjusted trade that is taken to the international financial calculations.

$ XRPA_r=\sum^SXS_{r,s}*WP_{s_r} $

$ MRPA_r=\sum^SMS_{r,s}*WP_s $

A purely optional adjustment to the relative price adjusted import and export levels is available for the model user who wishes to examine the hypothetical impact of changes in the terms of trade. The terms of trade parameter (termtrm ) is a multiplier with a normal value of 1.0. Higher values shift the terms of trade in the favor of Southern or less-developed regions (those with initial GDP per capita less than an amount, such as $5,000, specified by nsdiv ) and lower values favor Northern regions. The determination of North and South by initial GDP per capita and the fixing of those categories is important. 

if $ GDPPC_{r,t=1}>\mathbf{nsdiv} $ then $ XXRPA_r/\mathbf{termtrm} $

$ MRPA_r=MRPA_r*\mathbf{termtrm} $

if $ GDPPC_{r,t=1}\le\mathbf{nsdiv} $ then $ XXRPA_r=XXRPA_r*\mathbf{termtrm} $

$ MRPA_r=MRPA_r/\mathbf{termtrm} $

The adjustment to regional exports and imports for hypothetical terms-of-trade change can result in a failure of exports and imports to sum across regions to the same global total. At this point IFs thus normalizes regional exports and imports to a total value for world trade equal to the average of the current sums of exports and imports across regions.

Given final values for regional exports and imports it is possible to compute regional trade balances (TRADEBAL), using relative-price adjusted exports and imports.

$ TRADEBAL_r=XRPA_r-MRPA_r $

Stocks and Prices

IFs is fundamentally a general equilibrium model (GEM), but one in which inventory stocks serve as a temporary buffer between demand and supply and prices act to move the system towards equilibrium over time. The production available for final demand (PFD) and imports (MS) serve to increase stocks. Consumption (CS), investment (INVS), and government spending (GS) by sector of origin serve to decrease stocks, as do exports (XS).

$ ST_{r,s}=ST_{r,s,t-1}+PFD_{r,s}-CS_{r,s}-INVS_{r,s}-GS_{r,s}-XS_{r,s}+MS_{r,s} $

Prices (PRI) in IFs are quite important in the agricultural and energy models where they directly affect demand and supply through elasticities. In the economic model they have lesser impact, primarily through trade and secondarily through price-responsiveness of sectoral consumption. In addition, prices implicitly affect investment by destination, although for reasons of computational sequence IFs actually uses stock levels directly to redirect investment by sector. Prices in IFs are relative prices and are indices around initial base values of "1." They are based on stock levels and a second order stock change term.

$ PRI_{r,s}=PRI_{r,s,t-1}*(1+\frac{ST_{r,s}-dstl*STBASE_{r,s}}{STBASE_{r,s}})^\mathbf{elprst1}*(1+\frac{ST_{r,s}-ST_{r,s,t-1}*GDPR_{r,t=1}}{STBASE_{r,s}})^\mathbf{elprst2} $

where

$ STBASE_{r,s}=ZSP_{r,s}+MS_{r,s,t=1}*\frac{GDPPOT_r}{GDP_{r,t=1}} $

The stock base (STBASE) is the sum of gross production (important to large producers in an economic sector, whether they consume domestically or export) and initial imports scaled up by potential GDP growth (important to large importers, when domestic production is small). The desired level of stocks as a portion of the base (dstl ) is exogenous. 

Investment

</hgroup></header> The determination of investment by destination is a two-step procedure. First, IFs computes demand for investment by each sector (IFSDEM), responsive primarily to inventory levels. The base value of investment demand is dependent on the total level of gross capital formation (IGCF)—see its computation in the discussion of the social accounting matrix—and the portion of that directed into a particular sector (IDK) during the last time step. Parameters (elinst1 and elinst2 ) control the speed of adjustment. Second, IFs normalizes those demands to the total level of gross capital formation.

$ IFSDEM_{r,s}=IDK_{r,s,t-1}*IGCF_r*(1+\frac{ST_{r,s}-dstl*STBASE_{r,s}}{STBASE_{r,s}})^\mathbf{elinst1}*(1+\frac{ST_{r,s}-ST_{r,s,t-1}}{STBASE_{r,s}}^\mathbf{elinst2} $

where

$ STBASE_{r,s}=ZSP_{r,s}+MS_{r,s,t=1}*\frac{GDPPOT_r}{GDP_{r,t=1}} $

The above equation handles the sectors other than agriculture and energy. The model for agriculture provides investment need for that sector (IANEED), as does the energy model (IENEED).

$ IDSDEM_{r,s=1}=IANEED_r $

$ IDSDEM_{r,s=2}=IENEED_r $

To obtain actual investment by destination (IDS) we can distribute total investment (I) across sectors proportionately to their demands.

$ IDS_{r,s}=IGCF_r*\frac{IDSDEM_{r,s}}{\sum^SIDSDEM_{r,s}} $ As an indicator (and as the basis for sectoral investment splits in the next time cycle) we can compute the fractions going to each sector (IDK).

$ IDK_{r,s}=\frac{IDS_{r,s}}{IGCF_r} $

Capital stock (KS) in the next time period is simply the old capital stock plus investment by destination, minus depreciation (the capital stock divided by its lifetime, lks ), and minus the portion of capital destroyed as civilian damage (CIVDM) in war (see the policy model). The last term is, of course, normally zero.

$ KS_{r,s,t+1}=KS_{r,s}+IDS_{r,s}+\frac{KS_{r,s}}{\mathbf{lks}}-KS_{r,s}*CIVDM_r $

IFs makes no effort to represent a gestation period for capital of more than 1 year. Although it would be desirable to do so, it would also require a "look ahead" capability of the model to plan capital requirements several years in the future. Such a feature would add some realistic cyclical behavior to the model, but would also be somewhat difficult to control. And it is not the aim of IFs to capture business cycles. <header><hgroup>

Indicators

</hgroup></header> The economic model computes several indicators of interest to many IFs users. These include global product (WGDP), global product per capita (WGDPPC), an absolute measure of the per capita GDP gap between more developed (D) and less economically developed (L) regions (NSGAPA), and a relative measure of the same gap (NSGAPR). A parameter (nsdiv ) establishes the dividing point in thousand constant dollars between more and less developed.

$ WGDP=\sum^RGDP_r $

$ WGDPPC=\frac{WGDP}{WPOP} $

$ NSGAPA=(\frac{\sum^DGDP_R}{\sum^DPOP_r})-(\frac{\sum^LGDP_r}{\sum^LPOP_r}) $

$ NSGAPR=\frac{(\frac{\sum^DGDP_R}{\sum^DPOP_r})}{(\frac{\sum^GDP_r}{\sum^LPOP_r})} $

In an algorithmic procedure the system also computes a ratio of the GDP per capita (MER) in the countries that by average GDP per capita make up the richest 10 percent of global population to those that populate the bottom 10 percent (NSGAPRTB). </div></div>